Stocks and News
Home | Week in Review Process | Terms of Use | About UsContact Us
   Articles Go Fund Me All-Species List Hot Spots Go Fund Me
Week in Review   |  Bar Chat    |  Hot Spots    |   Dr. Bortrum    |   Wall St. History
Stock and News: Hot Spots
  Search Our Archives: 
 

 

Wall Street History

https://www.gofundme.com/s3h2w8

AddThis Feed Button

   

05/12/2000

Standard Oil, Part III

So in 1909, a Missouri circuit court ruled that Standard Oil
engaged in monopolistic practices. Standard Oil appealed.

Upon taking office in 1909, President William Howard Taft had
continued the antitrust cases begun by Teddy Roosevelt, adding
that he would enforce the Sherman Antitrust Act.

Taft, like TR, had no problem with big business as long as it
behaved itself, and he recommended that ''good'' trusts with a
capitalization of $100 million or more incorporate under a new
federal law, thus exempting them from suits brought by states.
A law embodying his ideas was introduced in both houses in
February 1910 but it failed to pass because it would have
destroyed the Act.

Taft launched 75 suits in 4 years, compared with 47 suits in 7
years by Roosevelt. But he seemed to misunderstand the whole
basis behind the antitrust act.

It''s interesting to note that before the Supreme Court ruled on the
Standard Oil case a future Justice, Louis Brandeis, wrote a letter
to the editor for "Survey" magazine.

"Is there not a causal connection between the development of
these huge, indomitable trusts and the horrible crimes now under
investigation?.Is it not irony to speak of the equality of
opportunity in a country cursed with bigness?"

And so it was that on May 15, 1911 the Court ruled against
Standard Oil by an 8 to 1 vote. At the time Harper''s magazine
noted that the case, along with a few others, had "been awaited
with countrywide suspense and attention.For months the
financial markets have virtually stood still awaiting their
settlement."

Actually, in doing some research on the numbers, this definitely
was the case. Between March 1 and May 15 the Dow Jones was
in a range of less than 4%, 81.32 to 84.53. On May 15 the Dow
closed at 82.71. The next day it rose to 84.63.

The Supreme Court upheld the Missouri decision to dissolve
Standard into some 37 subsidiary companies. But in its ruling
the Court announced a new "rule of reason" by which it could
decide whether a restraint of trade was "reasonable" or not and
what restraints of trade were allowable.

Put another way, the restraint of trade outlawed by the Sherman
Act is not to apply to every contract or combination in restraint
of trade, but only to those that do so unreasonably. In other
words, the Act was weakened.

Chief Justice Edward D. White wrote:

"[The Sherman Act was designed to prohibit] all contracts or acts
which were unreasonably restrictive of competitive conditions,
either from the nature or character of the contract or act or where
the surrounding circumstances were such as to justify the
conclusion that they had not been entered into or performed with
the legitimate purpose of reasonably forwarding personal interest
and developing trade, but on the contrary were of such a
character as to give rise to the inference or presumption that they
had been entered into or done with the intent to do wrong to the
general public and to limit the right of individuals."

[Actually, when you read it slowly, very slowly, it makes perfect
sense.]

The lower court had found Standard in violation of the Act and
had ordered its dissolution. As historian Bernard Schwartz
writes, "Yet, while the Court upheld the dissolution ruling, the
government had to accept an interpretation of the Sherman Act
which greatly reduced that law''s effectiveness. The Court ruled
that Standard''s practices constituted ''unreasonable'' restraint of
trade prohibited by the Sherman Act, rather than the type of
''reasonable'' restraint which the Act permitted. Thus was born
the most curious obiter dictum (incidental remark) ever indulged
in by the Court - the so-called ''rule of reason'' in antitrust cases."

The rule of reason was almost entirely the handiwork of Chief
Justice White, what Justice Holmes called "the Chief Justice''s
greatest dialectical coup." In practice it made prosecutions under
the Sherman Act far more difficult. At the same time, it
increased the judicial role in antitrust cases and ensured that the
law, "based though it might be on enactments by Congress,
would still be primarily judge-made law." [Schwartz]

Justice Harlan offered the lone dissent, one later labeled "a
passionate outburst seldom if ever equaled in the annals of the
Court."

To Harlan, the Court''s action was an example of "the tendency
to judicial legislation.(the) most alarming tendency of this day,
in my judgment, so far as the safety and integrity of our
institutions are concerned." In this case, the Court was led "to so
construe the Constitution or the statutes as to mean what they
want it to mean." The result was "that the courts may by mere
judicial construction amend the Constitution or an Act of
Congress."

Justice Holmes told a law clerk about the White opinion: "The
moment I saw that (the ''rule of reason'' clause) in the circulated
draft, I knew he had us. How could you be against that without
being for a rule of unreason?"

Author Charles Geisst concludes: "Standard Oil''s sins were too
great when weighed against its benefits to continue to exist as it
had. The company was ordered to break up, liquidating its stock
and returning the funds to its shareholders. The individual
companies went their respective ways, free to compete against
each other when the holding company no longer existed. The
federal government had successfully dissolved the largest and
most profitable business enterprise ever created."

Although Standard was physically broken up, Rockefeller
maintained his one-quarter ownership in the business, only this
time it was one-quarter of thirty-some new companies. J.P.
Morgan was said to have remarked, "How the hell is any court
going to compel a man to compete with himself?" The new set
of companies continued to dominate the markets well into the
1930s. Because of their size and vast network of suppliers and
distributors, the prices they set for their industries became the
norm. Smaller competitors broke ranks at their own peril.

Years later, in the 1950s, a group of scholars at the University of
Chicago took a hard look at the history of antitrust law. The
group came to be known as the Chicago School. One of them,
John McGee, studied Standard Oil to determine whether the
charges leveled against it in the original government suit were
justified. Author Geisst writes:

"McGee concluded that (they) had not used predatory pricing in
order to become a monopoly. His conclusion ran against the
common assumption that Rockefeller cut prices drastically in
order to force out his competitors.The fact that Rockefeller''s
customers feared his wrath if they did business with someone
else was central to the entire issue, but the net effect was that
predatory pricing was not involved. This was especially
important because predatory pricing had been a fundamental
assumption of antitrust until that time. If a company was a
monopoly, then it must practice predatory pricing. How else
could it have accumulated dominant market power? Obviously,
Rockefeller was able to accomplish it in other ways - for
example, making shipping more of a problem for his competitors
through arrangements he made with the railroads themselves."

In other words, while predatory pricing was one of the sins, one
couldn''t conclude that all monopolists practiced them.

And so our little history of Standard Oil is over. Hopefully you
have found it informative, especially in light of the ongoing
Microsoft saga.

Sources: "Monopolies in America," Charles Geisst
"The Growth of the American Republic, Vol. II,"
Morison, Commager, Leuchtenburg
"A History of the Supreme Court," Bernard Schwartz
"The Presidents," Henry Graff

Brian Trumbore



AddThis Feed Button

 

-05/12/2000-      
Web Epoch NJ Web Design  |  (c) Copyright 2016 StocksandNews.com, LLC.

Wall Street History

05/12/2000

Standard Oil, Part III

So in 1909, a Missouri circuit court ruled that Standard Oil
engaged in monopolistic practices. Standard Oil appealed.

Upon taking office in 1909, President William Howard Taft had
continued the antitrust cases begun by Teddy Roosevelt, adding
that he would enforce the Sherman Antitrust Act.

Taft, like TR, had no problem with big business as long as it
behaved itself, and he recommended that ''good'' trusts with a
capitalization of $100 million or more incorporate under a new
federal law, thus exempting them from suits brought by states.
A law embodying his ideas was introduced in both houses in
February 1910 but it failed to pass because it would have
destroyed the Act.

Taft launched 75 suits in 4 years, compared with 47 suits in 7
years by Roosevelt. But he seemed to misunderstand the whole
basis behind the antitrust act.

It''s interesting to note that before the Supreme Court ruled on the
Standard Oil case a future Justice, Louis Brandeis, wrote a letter
to the editor for "Survey" magazine.

"Is there not a causal connection between the development of
these huge, indomitable trusts and the horrible crimes now under
investigation?.Is it not irony to speak of the equality of
opportunity in a country cursed with bigness?"

And so it was that on May 15, 1911 the Court ruled against
Standard Oil by an 8 to 1 vote. At the time Harper''s magazine
noted that the case, along with a few others, had "been awaited
with countrywide suspense and attention.For months the
financial markets have virtually stood still awaiting their
settlement."

Actually, in doing some research on the numbers, this definitely
was the case. Between March 1 and May 15 the Dow Jones was
in a range of less than 4%, 81.32 to 84.53. On May 15 the Dow
closed at 82.71. The next day it rose to 84.63.

The Supreme Court upheld the Missouri decision to dissolve
Standard into some 37 subsidiary companies. But in its ruling
the Court announced a new "rule of reason" by which it could
decide whether a restraint of trade was "reasonable" or not and
what restraints of trade were allowable.

Put another way, the restraint of trade outlawed by the Sherman
Act is not to apply to every contract or combination in restraint
of trade, but only to those that do so unreasonably. In other
words, the Act was weakened.

Chief Justice Edward D. White wrote:

"[The Sherman Act was designed to prohibit] all contracts or acts
which were unreasonably restrictive of competitive conditions,
either from the nature or character of the contract or act or where
the surrounding circumstances were such as to justify the
conclusion that they had not been entered into or performed with
the legitimate purpose of reasonably forwarding personal interest
and developing trade, but on the contrary were of such a
character as to give rise to the inference or presumption that they
had been entered into or done with the intent to do wrong to the
general public and to limit the right of individuals."

[Actually, when you read it slowly, very slowly, it makes perfect
sense.]

The lower court had found Standard in violation of the Act and
had ordered its dissolution. As historian Bernard Schwartz
writes, "Yet, while the Court upheld the dissolution ruling, the
government had to accept an interpretation of the Sherman Act
which greatly reduced that law''s effectiveness. The Court ruled
that Standard''s practices constituted ''unreasonable'' restraint of
trade prohibited by the Sherman Act, rather than the type of
''reasonable'' restraint which the Act permitted. Thus was born
the most curious obiter dictum (incidental remark) ever indulged
in by the Court - the so-called ''rule of reason'' in antitrust cases."

The rule of reason was almost entirely the handiwork of Chief
Justice White, what Justice Holmes called "the Chief Justice''s
greatest dialectical coup." In practice it made prosecutions under
the Sherman Act far more difficult. At the same time, it
increased the judicial role in antitrust cases and ensured that the
law, "based though it might be on enactments by Congress,
would still be primarily judge-made law." [Schwartz]

Justice Harlan offered the lone dissent, one later labeled "a
passionate outburst seldom if ever equaled in the annals of the
Court."

To Harlan, the Court''s action was an example of "the tendency
to judicial legislation.(the) most alarming tendency of this day,
in my judgment, so far as the safety and integrity of our
institutions are concerned." In this case, the Court was led "to so
construe the Constitution or the statutes as to mean what they
want it to mean." The result was "that the courts may by mere
judicial construction amend the Constitution or an Act of
Congress."

Justice Holmes told a law clerk about the White opinion: "The
moment I saw that (the ''rule of reason'' clause) in the circulated
draft, I knew he had us. How could you be against that without
being for a rule of unreason?"

Author Charles Geisst concludes: "Standard Oil''s sins were too
great when weighed against its benefits to continue to exist as it
had. The company was ordered to break up, liquidating its stock
and returning the funds to its shareholders. The individual
companies went their respective ways, free to compete against
each other when the holding company no longer existed. The
federal government had successfully dissolved the largest and
most profitable business enterprise ever created."

Although Standard was physically broken up, Rockefeller
maintained his one-quarter ownership in the business, only this
time it was one-quarter of thirty-some new companies. J.P.
Morgan was said to have remarked, "How the hell is any court
going to compel a man to compete with himself?" The new set
of companies continued to dominate the markets well into the
1930s. Because of their size and vast network of suppliers and
distributors, the prices they set for their industries became the
norm. Smaller competitors broke ranks at their own peril.

Years later, in the 1950s, a group of scholars at the University of
Chicago took a hard look at the history of antitrust law. The
group came to be known as the Chicago School. One of them,
John McGee, studied Standard Oil to determine whether the
charges leveled against it in the original government suit were
justified. Author Geisst writes:

"McGee concluded that (they) had not used predatory pricing in
order to become a monopoly. His conclusion ran against the
common assumption that Rockefeller cut prices drastically in
order to force out his competitors.The fact that Rockefeller''s
customers feared his wrath if they did business with someone
else was central to the entire issue, but the net effect was that
predatory pricing was not involved. This was especially
important because predatory pricing had been a fundamental
assumption of antitrust until that time. If a company was a
monopoly, then it must practice predatory pricing. How else
could it have accumulated dominant market power? Obviously,
Rockefeller was able to accomplish it in other ways - for
example, making shipping more of a problem for his competitors
through arrangements he made with the railroads themselves."

In other words, while predatory pricing was one of the sins, one
couldn''t conclude that all monopolists practiced them.

And so our little history of Standard Oil is over. Hopefully you
have found it informative, especially in light of the ongoing
Microsoft saga.

Sources: "Monopolies in America," Charles Geisst
"The Growth of the American Republic, Vol. II,"
Morison, Commager, Leuchtenburg
"A History of the Supreme Court," Bernard Schwartz
"The Presidents," Henry Graff

Brian Trumbore